Agricultural composition and labor productivity
dc.creator | Blanco, Cesar |
dc.creator | Raurich, Xavier |
dc.date.accessioned | 2020-12-27T15:21:34Z |
dc.date.available | 2020-12-27T15:21:34Z |
dc.date.created | 2019-10-06 |
dc.date.issued | 2019-10-06 |
dc.identifier.citation | Acemoglu, D., Guerrieri,V. (2008).Capital de epening and nonbalanced economic growth, Journal of Political Economy, 116,467-498. |
dc.identifier.citation | Adamopoulos, T. and Restuccia, D. (2014). The size distribution of farms and international productivity differences, American Economic Review, 104, 1167-1697. |
dc.identifier.citation | Alvarez-Cuadrado, F., Van Long, N. and Poschke, M. (2017). Capital Labor Substitution, Structural Change and Growth. Theoretical Economics 12, 1229-1266. |
dc.identifier.citation | Banerjee, A. (2001). Contracting Constraints, Credit Markets, and Economic Devel- opment. In: Dewatripont, M., Hansen, L. and Turnovsky, S. (Eds). Advances in Eco- nomics and Econometrics: Theory and Applications, Eighth World Congress, Volume III, Chapter I, Cambridge University Press. |
dc.identifier.citation | Banerjee, A. and Duflo, E. (2005). Growth Theory through the Lens of Development Economics. In Handbook of Economic Growth, Chapter 7, Elsevier. |
dc.identifier.citation | Banerjee, A. and Moll, B. (2010). Why Does MisallocationPersist?, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 2,189.206. |
dc.identifier.citation | Chanda, A. and Dalgaard, C. (2008). Dualeconomies and international total factor productivity differences: channeling the Impact from institutions, trade, and geography, Economica, 75,629-661. |
dc.identifier.citation | Chen, C. (2017). Technology adoption, capital deepening, and international productivity differences, WP 584, University of Toronto. |
dc.identifier.citation | Chen, C. (2017). Untitled Land, Occupational choice, and agricultural productivity, American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, 9, 91-121. |
dc.identifier.citation | Cao, K. and Birchenall, J. (2013). Agricultural productivity, structural change, and economic growth in post-reform China, Journal of Development Economics, 104,165- 180. |
dc.identifier.citation | Caselli, F. (2015). Accounting for Cross-Country Income Differences, Handbook of Economic Growth, in: Philippe Aghion & Steven Durlauf (ed.), volume 1, 679-741. |
dc.identifier.citation | Caunedo, J. and Keller, E. (2016). Capital Obsolescence and Agricultural Productivity, 2016 Meeting Papers 686, Society for Economic Dynamics. |
dc.identifier.citation | Donovan, K. (2016). Agricultural risk, intermediate inputs, and cross-country productivity differences, mimeo. |
dc.identifier.citation | Gollin, D., Parente, S. ,and Rogerson, R. (2002). The role of agriculture in development, American Economic Review, 92, 160-164. |
dc.identifier.citation | Gollin, D., Parente,S., and Rogerson, R. (2007). The food problem and the evolution of international income levels, Journal of Monetary Economics, 54, 1230-1255. |
dc.identifier.citation | Gollin, D., Lagakos, D. and Waugh, M. (2013). The agricultural productivity gap, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 939-993. |
dc.identifier.citation | Gollin, D., Lagakos, D. and Waugh, M. (2014). Agricultural productivity differences across countries, American Economic Review , 104, 165-170. |
dc.identifier.citation | Gottlieb, C. and Grobovsek, J. (2019). Communal land and agricultural productivity, Journal of Development Economics, 138, 135-152. |
dc.identifier.citation | Hayashi, F. and Prescott, E. (2008). The Depressing Effect of Agricultural Institutions on the Prewar Japanese Economy, Journal of Political Economy, 116, 573-632. |
dc.identifier.citation | Karlan, D., Osei, R., Osei, I. Osei-Akoto and Udry, C. (2014). Agriculture decisions after relaxing credit and risk constraints, The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 129, 597-652. |
dc.identifier.citation | Kongsamut, P., Rebelo, S., Xie, X. (2001). Beyond balanced growth, Review of Economic Studies, 68, 869-882. |
dc.identifier.citation | Larson, D., R. Butzer, Y. Mundlak and Crego, A. (2000). Across-country database for sector investment and capital, The World Bank Economic Review, 14, 2, 371-391. |
dc.identifier.citation | Lagakos, D. and Waugh, M. (2013). Selection, Agriculture, and Cross-Country Productivity Differences, American Economic Review, 103, 948-980. |
dc.identifier.citation | Lucas, R. (1978). On the size distribution of business firms, The Bell Journal of Economics, 9, 508-523. |
dc.identifier.citation | Manuelli,R. E., and Seshadri, A. (2014). Frictionless Technology Diffusion: The Case of Tractors, American Economic Review, 104, 1368-91. |
dc.identifier.citation | Ngai, L. R., Pissarides, C. (2007). Structural change in a multisector model of growth, American Economic Review, 97, 429-443. |
dc.identifier.citation | Restuccia, D. and Santaeulalia-Llopis, R. (2017). Land Misallocation and Productivity, NBER Working Paper No. 23128. |
dc.identifier.citation | Restuccia, D., Yang, D. and Zhu, X. (2008).Agriculture and aggregate productivity: A quantitative cross-country analysis, Journal of Monetary Economics, 55,234.250. |
dc.identifier.citation | Valentinyi, Á. And Herrendorf, B. (2008). Measuring factor income shares at the sectoral level, Review of Economic Dynamics 11, 820-835 |
dc.identifier.citation | Vollrath, D. (2009). How Important are Dual Economy Effects for Aggregate Productivity?, Journal of Development Economics, 88, 325-334. |
dc.identifier.citation | Yang, D. and Zhu, X. (2013). Modernization of agriculture and long-term growth, Journal of Monetary Economics 60, 367-382. |
dc.identifier.uri | http://repositorio.bcp.gov.py/handle/123456789/126 |
dc.description.abstract | Labor productivity differences between developing and developed countries are much larger in agriculture than in non-agriculture. We show that cross-country differences in agricultural composition explain a substantial part of labor productivity differences. To this end, we group agricultural products into two sectors that are differentiated only by capital intensity. As the economy develops and capital accumulates, the price of labor- intensive agricultural goods relative to capital-intensive agricultural goods increases. This price change drives a process of structural change that shifts land and farmers to the capital-intensive sector, increasing labor productivity in agriculture. We illustrate this mechanism using a multisector growth model that generates transitional dynamics consistent with patterns of structural change observed in Brazil and other developing countries, and with cross-country differences in agricultural composition and labor productivity. Finally, we show that taxes and regulations that create a misallocation of inputs within agriculture also reduce the relative labor productivity. |
dc.format.extent | 39 páginas |
dc.format.mimetype | application/pdf |
dc.language.iso | eng |
dc.publisher | BCP |
dc.relation.ispartof | Documentos de Trabajo |
dc.relation.ispartofseries | Documento de Trabajo |
dc.relation.isversionof | Documento de Trabajo; N° 23 |
dc.rights.uri | http://creativecommons.org/publicdomain/zero/1.0/ |
dc.subject | CAMBIO ESTRUCTURAL |
dc.subject | PRODUCTIVIDAD DEL TRABAJO AGRÍCOLA |
dc.subject | INTENSIDAD DE CAPITAL |
dc.title | Agricultural composition and labor productivity |
dc.title.alternative | Composición agrícola y productividad laboral |
dc.type | Working Paper |
dc.subject.jel | O41 |
dc.subject.jel | O47 |
dc.subject.jelspa | O41 |
dc.subject.jelspa | O47 |
dc.subject.keyword | STRUCTURAL CHANGE |
dc.subject.keyword | AGRICULTURE LABOR PRODUCTIVITY |
dc.subject.keyword | CAPITAL INTENSITY |
dc.rights.accessRights | Open Access |
dc.type.spa | Documento de Trabajo |
dc.type.hasversion | Published Version |
dc.rights.cc | CC0 1.0 Universal |
dc.rights.spa | Acceso abierto |
Files in this item
This item appears in the following Collection(s)
This work is licensed under a Creative Commons Reconocimiento-NoComercial 4.0.This document has been deposited by the author (s) under the following certificate of deposit